top of page

Jevons Paradox

When more from less leads to more from more.



The Jevons Paradox is an economic theory that describes a counterintuitive phenomenon: improvements in the efficiency with which a resource is used often lead to increased, rather than decreased, consumption of that resource. This paradox challenges the conventional wisdom that efficiency gains naturally lead to conservation.


The paradox is named after the British economist William Stanley Jevons, who first noted this effect in his 1865 book "The Coal Question." Jevons observed that as technological improvements made coal-powered engines more efficient, the consumption of coal in England actually increased rather than decreased. This was because the efficiency improvements lowered the cost of using coal and expanded its range of economical uses, leading to a surge in demand that outpaced the savings from individual use.


The Rebound Effect


Closely related to the Jevons Paradox is the concept of the rebound effect. This effect occurs when some of the benefits gained from new technologies that improve efficiency are offset by changes in behavior that increase consumption. For example, if an innovation in automotive technology allows a car to travel further on a gallon of gas, this might lead to more frequent driving and longer distances, potentially negating any reductions in fuel consumption. When the rebound effect exceeds 100%, it results in higher overall resource use than before, embodying the Jevons Paradox.


The strength of the rebound effect often correlates with the level of market advancement. In developed markets where the means to manufacture and bring goods to consumers at scale, and where consumers are potentially more consumption-driven, the rebound effect tends to be stronger. This is partly because the initial cost reductions make the resource more accessible and its use more widespread.



Examples of Jevons Paradox



LED Lighting: As LED technology has advanced, these highly efficient bulbs have become ubiquitous. However, their low operating costs have encouraged broader and more innovative uses, from expansive city lighting projects to continuously lit commercial spaces, thus increasing overall electricity use for lighting.


Automobile Fuel Efficiency: Innovations in fuel efficiency have paradoxically led to increased fuel use in some cases. With the operating costs of driving lowered, consumers often choose to drive more frequently or purchase larger vehicles, which tend to consume more fuel overall, thus negating the gains from efficiency.


Computing Power: The increased efficiency of computer processors has dramatically reduced the cost per computation, leading to more extensive use of technology and data centers, which significantly increases the total energy consumption in the information technology sector.


Air Conditioning Systems: More efficient air conditioning systems have made cooling cheaper, leading not only to widespread adoption in new markets but also to lower thresholds for use, such as setting thermostats to more comfortable levels throughout more extensive periods of the year.


Agricultural Water Use: Improvements in irrigation technology have made it feasible to irrigate larger areas or grow more water-intensive crops, potentially increasing total water use in agriculture despite advancements in irrigation efficiency.


Plastic Use and Recycling: As recycling technologies advance and more plastics are recycled efficiently (or at least the public perception of recycling), the production and use of plastic products have increased because these materials are seen as less environmentally detrimental due to their recyclability.


Jevons Paradox as a Barrier to Sustainable Progress


The Jevons Paradox presents significant challenges to efforts aimed at decoupling GDP growth from resource and energy consumption. As economies grow and technologies advance, the paradox serves as a reminder that efficiency alone is not a panacea for sustainability. Instead, comprehensive strategies that incorporate efficiency gains with strong regulatory frameworks, cultural shifts in consumption, and perhaps pricing mechanisms that reflect the true environmental cost of resource use are required to truly reduce overall consumption.


We hear the idea of "cheap, abundant, clean energy for all" touted as a goal humanity is working towards. But in the context of Jevons Paradox, the price of energy is unlikely to decrease indefinitely. As the price of energy goes down, we figure out ways to use more of it for various purposes – even for things that serve little value. As the supply goes up, the price goes down, then demand goes up, and the price goes up. It's the paradox of resource abundance.


Instances Where Jevons Paradox Does Not Apply


The Jevons Paradox is not a universal rule. In some sectors, efficiency improvements do lead to net reductions in resource use. For instance, in highly regulated industries where resource use is capped or heavily taxed, efficiency gains translate directly into reduced consumption. Additionally, in markets where conservation efforts are culturally ingrained or where economic incentives are aligned with sustainability goals, the potential for reduced resource use remains tangible.


How to Overcome Jevons Paradox


In order to create a sustainable economy, we must find ways to overcome Jevons's Paradox. The rebound effect must be significantly less than 100%. We need to ensure that increased efficiency leads to decreased resource use.


Governments play a key role by enacting regulations that set limits on resource use. This includes imposing caps on emissions, enforcing energy standards for devices, and encouraging material recycling and pollution control.


Economic incentives and disincentives are also vital. Implementing pricing mechanisms that reflect the true environmental costs of resources—such as carbon taxes or cap-and-trade systems—makes consumption financially less attractive even with efficiency gains.


Promoting sustainable consumption is another vital approach. This involves shifting cultural norms and consumer behaviors through educational campaigns that emphasize the importance of reducing resource use and through incentives that encourage a minimalistic and environmentally conscious lifestyle.


Technological advancement should focus on the total environmental impact, not just isolated efficiency improvements. For instance, smart grids that optimize electricity use across an entire system can help reduce total energy consumption. Integrated resource planning across different sectors ensures that efficiency improvements align with broader environmental goals, considering the interdependencies of systems like water, energy, and food.


Encouraging manufacturers to adopt lifecycle analysis in their design processes ensures that products are not only efficient at one task but also have reduced environmental impacts throughout their lifespan. This includes better manufacturing and sourcing processes and enhanced recyclability.


Lastly, revising business models to focus more on providing services rather than selling products can further reduce resource use. For example, a shift from selling cars to providing mobility services incentivizes companies to maximize the efficiency and longevity of vehicles, thereby reducing the number sold.


While the Jevons Paradox highlights a critical and often overlooked aspect of resource consumption, it also underscores the complexity of managing technological progress and economic growth in a sustainable way. Recognizing when and where the paradox applies is essential for engineering solutions and creating effective environmental policies and moving towards a truly sustainable future.



Questions for you:
  • What's another example of Jevons Paradox?

  • What is a potential solution to the paradox? How can we ensure that efficiency improvements lead to decreased resource consumption?

  • What product or industry is ripe for efficiency gains?

bottom of page